Decision ris proposal for national licensing of the property occupations


Wider economic impacts on the Australian economy



Yüklə 2,69 Mb.
səhifə23/45
tarix01.08.2018
ölçüsü2,69 Mb.
#65364
1   ...   19   20   21   22   23   24   25   26   ...   45

3.Wider economic impacts on the Australian economy


Computable general equilibrium (CGE) modelling was undertaken to quantify the potential economy-wide (or flow-on) effects of an increase in efficiency that is predicted to result from the introduction of national licensing for the property occupations in Australia. This includes the potential impact of improvements in labour mobility, which allows resources to be more efficiently allocated across the economy. 78

The purpose of using a CGE model for this analysis is to demonstrate the potential economy-wide impacts of the national reform to the licensing of the property occupations. CGE is a highly regarded and widely applied tool to measure the economic impacts of policy and regulatory change. For example, this approach has been used to measure the impacts of key reforms, including:



  • national competition policy79

  • climate change policies, including emissions trading and a carbon tax80

  • the COAG national reform agenda81

  • tariff reforms.

CGE modelling can provide insights into the economic impacts of reforms that an analysis of the direct costs and benefits cannot. Direct measures are valuable because they can target the specific, immediate impacts of change, focused on particular stakeholders or sectors in the economy. CGE modelling takes the analysis further by acknowledging the interdependence and interrelationships between sectors in the economy. When done appropriately, it provides a picture of how reforms have impacts across the economy, including on those sectors not directly affected by the reforms.

It should be noted that the CGE modelling was not updated from the Consultation RIS. The differences in the structure of the proposed model and changes to assumptions underlying the model between the Consultation RIS and Decision RIS would impact these results. Accordingly, the CGE modelling results are only indicative of the type and scale of the overall long-term impacts on the economy if national licensing is adopted.


The shock to the model – the scenario modelled for this Decision Regulation Impact Statement


Under national licensing requirements, barriers to entry for the property occupations in each jurisdiction are expected to be reduced through, for example, reduction in costs for licensing and an increase in the readiness to work between jurisdictions. This is translated as:

  • an increase in efficiency of labour in property services

  • an increase in efficiency of capital in property services

  • a reduction in multiple licence fees that those in the property occupations pay to government.

Additionally, the reform will affect the amount of public administration that the state and territory governments consume, as they will have to process fewer licences.

To model each of these impacts, calculations based on the results of the cost–benefit analysis have been drawn on. Only the ongoing costs and benefits from the cost–benefit analysis have been modelled.


Key results

45.Key economic mechanisms in play – moving from the initial shock to the wider economy


It is not appropriate to sum the results of the economy-wide CGE analysis and direct impacts estimated through the cost–benefit analysis. Instead, the economy-wide results should be interpreted as providing insights into the mechanisms by which the direct impacts flow through the economy and lead to benefits in those areas of the economy that are not directly affected by the change in licensing arrangements.

46.The impacts of an increase in efficiency


When viewed in the context of the Australian economy, it is to be expected that the economy-wide effects of a labour and capital efficiency shock to the property services component of the business services industry will be small. Nevertheless, the results illustrate the economic mechanisms that may be in play as the efficiency gain flows through the wider economy.

The increase in the productivity of labour in the property services sector decreases production costs for users of these services, particularly the business services industry. In the CGE framework, this is passed on to users of business services in the form of decreased prices.

In turn, other industries in the economy experience positive flow-on effects, resulting from a decrease in the cost of production, and hence prices, across many industries in the Australian economy. This mechanism is illustrated in Figure 4.1.

Figure 4.1: Flow-through effects of an increase in productivity in the business services industry

productivity increases, per unit labour cost decreases, cost of production decreases, prices decrease, cost of production for interrealted industries decreases

Similarly, an increase in the efficiency of capital draws down the cost of production in the business services industry. In the CGE framework, this is passed on to users of business services in the form of decreased prices.

In turn, other industries in the economy experience positive flow-on effects, resulting from a decrease in the cost of production, and hence prices, across many industries in the Australian economy.

47.The impacts of a decrease in fees paid by licensees


A decrease in the fees that property licensees pay to government results in an increase in the posttax income for the property industry. This results in a higher level of income across Australia, leading to a higher level of household consumption.

48.Macroeconomic results


At a macroeconomic level, the results may be viewed from both sides of GDP, that is, the income side and the expenditure side. This is illustrated in Figure 4.2.

Figure 4.2: Income and expenditure side of GDP

the income side shows labour, land, capital and productivity/efficiency with arrows pointing toward gross domestic product. the expenditure side shows household consumption, investment, government consumption and trade balance with arrows poiting toward gross domestic product.

The modelling shows that national licensing for the property occupations is likely to increase GDP in a typical year by approximately $79 million.

The rise in income drives an increase in consumption, which is a proxy of welfare, of $35 million in a typical year. The increase in consumption is driven by an increase in household consumption. The consumption of the Australian Government increases; however, this is offset by a decrease in state government consumption. The harmonisation of licences induces an increase in investment in Australia, which increases by $33 million in a typical year. This additional investment leads to an increase in the capital stock in Australia of $21 million.

The harmonisation of the property licences causes a real depreciation of the Australian exchange rate, as domestic goods and services become cheaper relative to foreign goods and services. This causes exports to increase by $33 million in a typical year. While imports become relatively more expensive than domestically produced goods and services, increases in investment and household consumption boost demand for imports, resulting in an increase in imports of $19 million in a typical year.

These key macroeconomic results are summarised in Figure 4.3.

Figure 4.3: Key macroeconomic results, $ million for a typical year

a bar graph with five bars in descending height. the vertical axis has a scale from bottom to top reading zero to ninety million dollars. the horizontal axis reads from left to right gdp, household consumption, investment, exports and imports.

Source: Monash Multi-region Forecasting Model and PricewaterhouseCoopers.


49.Industry results


The industries that benefit under the modelled scenario are those that face lower costs of production (due to the reduction in the price of business services), together with those that are positively affected by the improvement in the terms of trade (that is, export-intensive industries).

Figure 4.4 illustrates the impact on key sectors in the economy. The mining and construction sectors benefit the most from the reform in terms of growth. The benefits associated with the mining sector appear to be associated with the significant proportion of transient workers in the mining sector. It is important, however, to be mindful of the limitations of input–output (I–O) modelling when assessing the point estimates of the industry-specific impacts. A key limitation is the presence of significant standard error in some elements of the I–O matrix, thereby rendering point estimates imprecise.



Figure 4.4: Key industry results, percentage increase


a bar chart with seven bars. the vertical axis reads a range of percentages from 0.000 percent at the bottom to 0.012 percent at the top. the horizontal axis reads agriculture, mining, manufacturing, utilities, construction, trade and services.

Yüklə 2,69 Mb.

Dostları ilə paylaş:
1   ...   19   20   21   22   23   24   25   26   ...   45




Verilənlər bazası müəlliflik hüququ ilə müdafiə olunur ©muhaz.org 2024
rəhbərliyinə müraciət

gir | qeydiyyatdan keç
    Ana səhifə


yükləyin