Now for some algebra based on the following simple diagrams, with ‘O’ as the ‘origin’ (or intersection) of the horizontal (t) and vertical L) axes.
Figure 2.
Figure 2(b) shows two screeningcurves that involve two types of equipment, X and Y. (If you want more information about screening curves, examine the elementary book by Professor Fisher (1974).) If the base load is constant at unity (= 1), but the peak load area is as in Figure 2(c), where the entire load (base+peak) is constant at 2 for time t”, then it can be shown by some simple algebra of the kind presented below that the peak is carried by Y. But if it is as in Figure 2(d), where it is also constant at 2, but must be carried for a time t’. then some algebra indicates that the entire load (base + peak) is carried by X, which is clearly (capital intensive) equipment that is generally associated with only the base load. In case you encounter the expression merit order – which is the issue here – it is fundamentally about the cost and correct deployment of equipment..
As for the load curve in Figure 2(a), that figure is not related to the other three diagrams, but it has a pedagogical value. While O-LT is a base load (in that it is on the line for the entire period under discussion), and O–L(0) is an unambiguous peak load according to the diagram, it may be necessary to introduce the expression intermediateload for all or a part of LT-L”, and usually with some ambiguity about what kind of equipment should carry this part of the total load. For instance, In Figure 2(d), while we might identify the smaller rectangle as the peak load area, with a constant peak load, the cost situation is apparently such that the entire load is serviced by capital intensive equipment. In addition, some readers might feel that rather than identifying a unique peak load – e.g. O–L(O) in Figure 2-(a) – the triangle next to L”–L(0) should be called the peak load. To clarify some aspects of this mystery, some algebra is useful, so that on a cold winter evening in Stockholm or Siberia, you can get your beauty sleep without wondering whether you will have to identify peak or off-peak loads on your next examination, or fret about definitions and exact sizes of generating equipment.
As for the algebra, F is fixed cost and v variable (e.g. fuel) cost. As shown in 2(b), we have a situation where at time t*, the total costs are equal. Algebraically we write:
Next, assume that regardless of how things appear in the Figure 2(b), we consider using only the X type of equipment to supply the peak load in Figure 2(c). The total cost is then;
TCxx = Fx + Fx + Tvx + t”vx (2) If we had used both X and Y (which is obviously the correct choice): TCxy = Fx + Fy + Tvx + t”vy (3) The next step is to compare these : TCxx – TCxy = (Fx + Fy) + t*(vy – vx) (4) And using (vy - vx) from (1), this can be written as: TCxx - TCxy = (Fx – Fy)/[(t* - t”)/t*] (5)
Since Fx > Fy and t* > t”), the right hand side of (5) is positive, and so TCxx is larger than TCxy. Thus we confirm with some simple algebra that it is uneconomic to use only the X type of equipment to service the entire ( base + peak) load, as of course we immediately comprehended if we understood the story being told in Figures 2(b) and 2(c). Furthermore, in this exercise, comparing t” with any t enables us to determine, for any load, whether the addition of an extra unit (e.g. kW) of capacity should be X or Y type equipment. To be precise, as long as t* > t, then Y type equipment should be added, while if t* < t, then X type equipment should be added. Once again: the issue here is the correct merit order, based on cost minimization!
Now let me confess that there is something important that I overlooked in the first version of this lecture. The exact appearance of the load curve is relatively unimportant, and the same is true of the units used for the load: theoretically it doesn’t make any difference if we measure load in kilowatts or megawatts. The thing that is important is where the screening curves intersect. Readers should therefore make sure that they can calculate the values of ‘t’ (=t*) in the diagrams above where the screening curves intersect. Secondary school algebra is all you need here.
I can also present readers with a question on the next examination that I will give in energy economics: Explain why, without mathematics, the peak load in Figure 4(d) will be serviced by what is usually thought of as (capital intensive) base load equipment? The answer is – as is always the case in economic theory – that if we used the other equipment, the (variable) cost normally involved in servicing the peak load would be greater than the cost for the additional capital intensive equipment.
A few more comments might be useful. With ‘t’ the time that equipment is on the line, then if as above we are thinking about a period of one day, we must have t ≤ 24 (hours), while if we are considering a year then we have t ≤ 8760 (hours). Here we might write in a general sort of way t ≤ T (hours). We might also have the case of a day in which the base load is 1000 kW, which is on the line for 24 hours, but during 8 hours an additional 1000 kW must be generated. The peak load is thus 2000 kW, while the off-peak load is 1000 kW. (Trivially, the base load plus the maximum value of the non-base load is the peak load, although obviously this can create some algebraic difficulties).
Readers who have come this far without feeling frustrated should be very satisfied, but before congratulating yourself go through the above presentation once more. There is often a certain amount of ambiguity in these matters, and I don’t mind saying that you should always have your bunkum detectors available when you are dealing with some of the more complex energy and environmental enigmas. For instance, generally the peak load represents only a small fraction of the demand for electricity, and so it can happen that only a portion of the generating capacity serving a given load is in use. But since the available generating equipment must be able to satisfy the maximum demand that may appear in the system, capacityfactors – the actual number of hours that equipment is operating in relation to hours in a year – for peak load equipment are often quite small. This is unavoidable, and if you need to turn to GOOGLE for more information, the items to examine are peak loads, shortcircuits and overloads!
OIL AND MONEY: Futures and Options Earlier versions of this chapter did not include the present section, however some earlier readers – to include the important researcher and my former colleague from the University of New South Wales (Australia), Tom Moder Mozina – believe that this new section is useful for beginning energy economics students, as long as it does not contain any unnecessary math. My favorite futures market story – involving two young financial geniuses named Millicent and Condi – is in the next chapter, but since that story is fiction, I will mostly – but not entirely – keep to the ‘straight and narrow’ here, without surrogates, and with crude oil and money the subject of the exercise. Incidentally OIL AND MONEY is the title of an up-market conference in London (UK) every year, and reading this section will be useful before you give a brilliant talk there.
Commodity futures markets (e.g. oil) operate as follows. Against a background of spectators ‘betting’ on the direction and size of commodity price movements by buying and selling futures contracts, an impersonal agency can be created which permits producers, consumers, inventory holders and other dealers in physical products (e.g. physical oil) to reduce (i.e. ‘hedge’) undesired price risk. As simple as this turns out to be in both theory and practice, there are a great many misunderstandings about these markets. For instance, the Fox News commentator Bill O’Reilly once suggested that “little guys in Las Vegas” play a key role in these markets. Bill was not correct.
Other observers have also insisted that the oil futures markets (or markets for paper oil) were responsible for the devastating price rise of crude oil in the summer of 2008, but as will be noted below, futures trading helps to decrease the volatility and level of oil prices by facilitating the reduction of price risk. Furthermore, the oil price shock of 2008 was almost entirely due to demand outrunning supply in the markets for physical oil. This is something that you should never forget, and it is so obvious that you should never waste your time discussing this issue with persons who think otherwise.
What futures trading can do is to encourage producers and consumers to carry larger (physical) inventories of oil, because the risk associated with carrying these inventories can be lessened by ‘shorting’ (= selling) futures. As a result, these inventories are available to help dampen upward price spikes or sustained price shocks like the bad news in 2008. There are plenty of claims that futures trading results in less ambiguous (or strange) price movements, which may or may not be true, but it appears accurate to say that there is an upgrading in the efficiency of crude oil markets due to more information being made available to market participants. Information that someday you and smart people like you may be employed to help interpret.
The speculative component of futures trading is simple. If a person whom we shall define as a speculator believes that the price of oil is going to rise, he or she opens a position by buying futures contracts (or going long). These contracts are also forward contracts in that delivery conditions are stipulated on them relating to a specified amount of oil, delivered during a certain month to one or more specified locations. Something that must be noted (and remembered) is that when buying (or selling) a futures contract, a security deposit (called margin) must be paid your broker in case the price does not move the way you think it will, and your position loses money. (For instance, if you go long and the price declines.) In addition, dealings in futures take place with a broker, and not at the futures exchange, and so a brokers fee is involved.
Focus on the following. Although delivery of the commodity is usually possible, it would not take place to your home or business, but almost always to some out-of-the-way location. Put another way, futures markets are not about physical delivery, but about opening positions and closing them by reverse transactions. If you open a position in oil by buying (going long), you can avoid taking delivery of the item if, at any time before the contract matures (i.e. expires), an offsettingsale is made of a contract for the same amount of oil, referred to the same delivery month. (Offsetting = reversing.)
Offsetting is always possible in a viable futures market: for instance, you might phone your broker and open a position by buying a futures contract, while just a few hours (or a few weeks) later you phone her and close your position with the sale of a contract. As noted, if you opened a position by buying a contract (or going long), the offsetting action is selling a contract (or going short).
If it happens that the long contract was sold for a higher price than it was purchased, then a profit has been made – assuming that the difference between the sell and buy price is greater than the broker’s fee, which is almost always the case. Similarly, if the speculator thinks that the price of oil will decline, he or she opens a position by selling a contract (going short), and if the price actually declines, a profit is usually made when you close your position by buying a contract (going long). Think about it: as John Garfield said in a film, buying low and selling high can make you rich.
OBSERVE; you walk into a brokerage, pay the broker a fee and sell a contract (go short) for a certain amount of oil. You need not discuss your reasons for this action. Then you walk out the door, and if the price does fall within the (maturity) period specified on the contract, and the broker’s fee is less than the difference between the sell and buy price, you make a profit when you close your position with a buy! Once again: you opened this transaction by selling a futures contract, and closed it by buying one. The actual possession of the physical commodity is irrelevant!
The mechanics of this operation will be explained in a kind of soap opera in the next chapter, and without any mathematics, but obviously a partial explanation may be necessary now, because what we have in the discussion just above is selling a commodity (e.g. oil) without owning any, However, as you will find out, the process is as easy (or easier) to understand than buying and selling shares (i.e. stocks). Moreover, buying or selling oil futures – which are sometimes called ‘paper oil’ – does not involve your coming into contact with physical oil, or knowing anything about physical oil other than your belief that you know in which direction the oil price is going to move.
Now for an example of hedging, or guarding against undesired price rises or falls. Suppose that every room in your house – as well as your garage and garden – contains barrels of oil, stacked as high as you can get them, because a friend who works for Gordon Gekko has assured you that the price of oil is going to rise, and when it rises you can sell this oil and make a lot of money. But after Mr Gekko was indicted for telling false tales about various commodity price movements, you wonder if it might not be best to take out some price insurance on this oil. In other words, to hedge against the price falling instead of rising, which will involve going short in futures!
Assume that 1000 barrels of oil are being kept on your property. Then you might sell a futures contract for 1000 barrels, because if the physical oil you have on your property loses value (i.e. its price falls), the ‘sell’ contract that you started with gains value: It gains value because of the profit you can make with an offsetting buy.
What is this example all about again? It is about opening a position by calling your broker and selling a contract at the then prevailing futures market price (going short), and later calling your broker before the expiry date on your sell contract and making a purchase (going long) at the then prevailing futures market price. Thus, a possible fall in the price of physical oil could be totally or partially compensated for by a fall in the price of your paper oil, and here you can provide a simple numerical example in which a gain is made by making an offsetting buy of a contract at a lower price than that at which you opened your position: a buy which closes your position, and gains you a profit. Understanding this means that you understand what part futures contracts play in obtaining price insurance. Now I suggest that you go through the above discussion more slowly, perhaps with a colleague or two, and discuss the kind of hedging that you would do if you were a buyer of oil, and wanted to guard against a price rise.
Next we can turn to options. It is a fairly common belief that options are more difficult to understand than futures. This is not true, and it behooves everyone with even a slight interest in the subject to learn a few things about the basic mechanics of this particular ‘derivative’ – where a derivative is an asset (= something of value) whose value is dependent on what happens in the market for another asset. In this case, paper oil (= oil futures or oil options) whose value depends on the value of physical oil.
Sticking with oil, an option provides the buyer (of an option) the right to buy or sell a given amount of an underlying commodity at a fixed price – called the exercise (or strike) price – within a given period that (as with futures) is called the expiry or maturity period. (The asset or commodity in question is often just called the ‘underlying’, and the end of the period during which the option can be traded is called the expiry or maturity value of the period.) If the transactor buys an option that involves purchasing the underlying, he or she has bought a call option. If the option involves selling the underlying, he or she has bought a put option! Remember these words!
And please note the following: unlike a futures contract, an option contract does not have to be exercised by buying, selling, or taking delivery. It can simply be discarded if the purchaser so desires – in other words, no reversing transaction is necessary. In fact the seller of the option, generally called the writer, wants nothing more than to see the option go unexercised. An important point here is that an American-type option can be exercised whenever the option buyer feels like it, so long as the exercising takes place before the maturity date, while a European-type option can only be exercised at the expiry date, assuming that the buyer prefers exercising to dumping the option. Most options in every part of the world are American options.
When the initial transaction takes place, the buyer of a put or call option pays what is called a premium to the option writer. This premium is the option price, and ideally it would be formed in an auction type market (such as a stock exchange) by the forces of supply and demand. (NOTE: it is the premium and not the exercise price that is the price of the option). It also happens that options are usually sold over-the-counter (OTC) basis by financial institutions.
Once a position is opened in a futures market, it stays open until the expiry date of the contract or, in the usual case, is closed by a reverse transaction. (QUESTION: explain what that means?) If no reverse transaction (= offsetting transaction) takes place, then oil will be received or delivered. But with options a right is being purchased for the purchase (and perhaps delivery) of a commodity (e.g. oil) at any time over the maturity period of the option, and conditions of one sort or another may convince the buyer to simply tear up the option, thus forfeiting the premium.
Now for an example. Suppose Sven purchased some options contracts from the star trader Millicent on March 15 which gave him the right to purchase 1000 barrels of oil from Millie by April 1st for 100 dollars a barrel (= $100/b). The premium for this transaction is $6/b, and so Sven immediately turns 6000 dollars over to Millicent.
Why would he find this arrangement attractive. One reason might be that the present price is $98/b, and remembering what happened in 2008 (when the price of oil moved rapidly to $147/b), paying a premium of $6/b in order to purchase 1000 barrels of oil for 100 dollars a barrel seems like a bargain. As for Millicent’s she looks at the existing oil price several times a day, and talks with various people who know a lot about that subject, and they have convinced her that the price of oil is on its way down.
Suppose Millicent and her sources are correct, and the market price of oil declines sharply to $90/b. Then Sven tears up his option and buys his oil on the open market, and Millicent has 6000 dollars. Male sure that you understand the action here.
Now, suppose Sven is selling oil, and he wanted to obtain some money via a transaction with Millicent. After dinner one night in Stockholm’s Club Alexandra, he informed Millicent on March 15th, with the oil price at $100/b, that he would sell her 1000 barrels of oil at any time between that date and April 1st for $105/b, but to obtain that arrangement she must immediately pay him a premium of 3 dollars a barrel.
She agrees, because on the previous day her friend and colleague Condi Montana informed her that the oil price was going to escalate because there was a likelihood that Monaco was going to attempt to seize the nearest ski resorts in France, and wars or rumors of wars almost always led to increases in the prices of fossil fuels, especially oil.
Condi was right. Monoco unexpectedly mobilized and armed all the employees of the casinos, and the oil price shot up to $114/b, because wars anywhere in the world have a tendency to influence the oil price. Millicent exercised her option, receiving 1000 barrels of oil from Sven for which she paid 105 dollars a barrel, plus the 3 dollars a barrel she paid as a premium. Her oil was delivered by Sven the next day, at which time she immediately sold it on the spot market for $114/b, which meant that her profit per barrel was $113/b – $108/b = $5/b. What was her total profit? Now suppose that Sven was buying oil. What kind of option deal would he propose to Millicent?
REFERENCES
Banks, Ferdinand E. (2014). Energy and Economic Theory. Singapore, New York and
London: World Scientific
______ . (2007). The Political Economy of World Energy: An Introductory Textbook.
Singapore, New York and London: World Scientific.
______. (2000). Energy Economics: A Modern Introduction. Norwell Massachusetts: