This book explores the impact of the 1917 Revolution on factory life



Yüklə 4,02 Mb.
səhifə22/32
tarix21.03.2018
ölçüsü4,02 Mb.
#46139
1   ...   18   19   20   21   22   23   24   25   ...   32

Conclusion

The labour movements of Western Europe were dominated by skilled
artisans for most of the nineteenth century. Trades, such as tailors,
shoemakers, cabinet-makers, carpenters and the building trades,
spearheaded the radical and labour movements.1 In contrast, the
factory proletariat, which consisted to a large extent of women and
children, was, with certain exceptions, badly organised and political-
ly quiescent.2 Only in the last quarter of the nineteenth century did
trade unionism begin to expand beyond the ranks of an elite of
artisans and skilled factory craftsmen. The evolution of the Petrograd
labour movement was far more telescoped that its counterparts in the
countries of Western Europe. Although the number of strikes and
informal labour organisations grew rapidly during the last quarter of
the nineteenth century, it was not until the 1905 Revolution that a
formal labour movement was inaugurated. Although artisans played
an important part in creating trade unions and socialist
organisations,3 by 1917 the labour movement of the Russian capital
was based predominantly on workers in factory industry, workers
employed in huge enterprises which were among the most modern in
the world. Whilst this working class corresponded in some respects to
the Marxian model of the modern working class, since it was
employed in large-scale machine industry, in other respects, it was
not yet a fully-developed proletariat. Within its ranks, urbanised,
hereditary proletarians were still outnumbered by newcomers to
industry, who retained strong ties to the countryside. The labour
movement which was re-established in Petrograd after the February
Revolution, therefore, had a hybrid character. Based on the modern
factory rather than the artisanal workshop, it embraced a gamut of
types of workers from the traditional artisan, to the skilled worker of




the modern assembly plant, to the peasant migrant worker, so
familiar in the Third World today.

The factory workforce of Petrograd was highly differentiated by


degree of proletarianisation, by skill and wage-level, by gender, age
and education. Each of these variables had its own effectivity within
the struggles of the working class in 1917, and, in particular
circumstances, could become ‘overdetermined’, as for instance, in the
conflict between male and female workers over redundancies, or the
conflict between skilled and unskilled workers during the metal-union
contract negotiations. Nevertheless, one can crudely generalise, and
say that within the workforce in 1917 there were two broad groups of
workers: the first, consisting of proletarianised, skilled, literate, male
workers, who comprised around 40% of the total factory workforce;
the second, consisting of workers new to industry - mainly rural
migrants, women and youth. The first group - sometimes called by
contemporaries ‘cadre’ workers — should not, as a whole, be
considered a ‘labour aristocracy’, for although there were aristocratic
strata within it — the best-paid type-setters in the print trade, the
starshie in the armaments factories or the glass-blowers of the glass
industry — the majority of skilled men, whilst earning higher wages
and being culturally distinct from the new workers, lacked the strong
craft traditions on which the power of the ‘labour aristocracy’ in
nineteenth-century Britain had been based. Moreover, their skills
were not the all-round skills of the artisanal workshop, but the more
specialised skills of the modern factory. The widespread introduction
of the new technology of mass production during the First World War
facilitated the big increase in numbers of the second group of new
workers. The expansion of mass production in the metal and chemical
industries allowed the rapid absorption of new workers into semi-
skilled and unskilled jobs. The working-class women, the peasant
youths and the urban petit-bourgeois who poured into the factories of
the capital had little prior experience of wage-work in modern
industry, but it did not take long to train them to operate automatic
machinery or tend assembly lines. They quickly adapted to the
fevered tempo of work in the war industries and to the discipline of the
piece-rate system. The young, in particular, were soon at home in the
factory and the city. Nevertheless, in 1917 the new workers were still
culturally distinct from the ‘cadre’ workers, who tended to regard
them as the ‘backward masses’.

The existence of two broad social groups within the workforce was






by no means a new phenomenon brought about by the war. As far
back as the 1880s, contemporaries had noted the phenomenon and
had speculated on the revolutionary propensities of each group.
Kropotkin, one of the fathers of Russian anarchism, predicted that it
would be the spontaneous militancy of the fabrichnie, the down-
trodden peasants and women of the textile mills, which would spark
off the social revolution.4 In contrast, Plekhanov, the father of
Russian Marxism, envisaged that the zavodskie, or skilled workers of
the metal plants, would provide the basis of the revolutionary
movement, because of their greater proletarianisation, literacy and
leisure time.5 The experience of 1917 suggests that the two groups
played different, but largely complementary roles in the revolution-
ary process. Those who built the labour movement were the ‘cadre’
workers, especially metalworkers, for they had more time and money
at their disposal, were at home in the factory, were more literate, had
experience of informal shop-floor organisation and a degree of
job-control, and were thus better placed to participate in labour and
political activities. The new workers, on the other hand, were often
more turbulent than the ‘cadre’ workers because they combined the
manifold discontents of the low-paid worker with the grievances of the
poor peasants and the specific oppressions of women and youth.
Their militancy, however, was often of an explosive, sectional and
volatile kind, and tended to threaten the attempts of the factory
committee and trade-union leaders to build sustained, formal
organisations. The labour leaders were not unsympathetic to the
plight of the new workers, but they sought to direct their militancy
into organised channels. They had some success in this, for women
and peasant workers began in 1917 to engage in organised pursuit of
their goals and to join trade unions. Young workers in particular,
displayed a remarkable propensity for self-organisation. In this sense,
working-class unity became a reality after February, in spite of
profound divisions within the factory workforce. Yet contradictions of
interest - between skilled and unskilled, men and women, young and
old — remained: contradictions which labour leaders were reluctant to
recognise. For while they aspired to bring the inexperienced and
badly-off groups of workers into the orbit of the labour movement,
they were unwilling to make special provision for the particular needs
of the unskilled, the peasant migrants, working women or of youths.
As a result, the participation of the latter in labour organisations and
in revolutionary politics more generally, remained fairly tenuous. As




the economy collapsed in early 1918, contradictions of interest
between different groups of workers came to the fore, with the result
that the unity of the previous year began to fall apart.

The tsarist factory was, in certain respects, a microcosm of the wider


society. The structure of authority, the conditions of work, the low
wages placed workers in a semi-servile position, and they welcomed
the February Revolution as emancipation from this ‘serfdom’.
Workers saw the overthrow of the Romanov dynasty as the signal to
create a democratic, or ‘constitutional’ factory order: firstly, by
expelling the most unpopular administrators and, secondly, by
establishing representative institutions to promote their interests as
wage-earners within both the factory and society at large. In a very
short time, workers won the eight-hour day and big wage-increases to
compensate for wartime inflation. The Petrograd employers’ associa-
tion, having long resisted a more liberal industrial-relations policy,
quickly reconciled itself to the ‘constitutional’ order in the factories,
and conceded the greater part of the workers’ demands.

The factory committees were the greatest gain made by workers as


a result of the February Revolution. They had their roots in the
tradition of the starosty, and perhaps, too, in the informal job control of
skilled workers, which was increasingly threatened by rationalisation
and de-skilling. The committees were strongest in the state sector,
where skilled workers of a defencist persuasion temporarily took over
the running of their enterprises, in order to ensure that production for
the war effort was not put in jeopardy. It was out of this experience
that the ideas of workers’ control of production and collegial
management were born. In the private sector the factory committees
at first had largely trade-union functions, for it took some time for the
unions to re-establish themselves, but everywhere the committees
took on a wide range of tasks within and without the workplace. They
asserted their right to monitor hiring and firing, to supervise the
general running of the factory, and they intervened in areas as diverse
as food-supply, education and law and order. Because state power
was relatively ineffective, the committees became a central part of
that ‘counter-state’ which was built up by workers between February
and October, and in whose name the Bolsheviks seized power.6

The trade unions took some time to get off the ground, especially in


the metal industry, where the factory committees were strongest.
Throughout 1917 the unions were less influential than the commit-




tees, for the latter were more popular, more democratic and more
powerful than the unions. It would be wrong, however, to minimise
the importance of the unions, for they grew at a remarkable rate,
becoming genuine mass organisations, and playing a crucial part in
the revolutionary process. Craft unionism proved relatively weak in
Petrograd, guild traditions never having been as strongly rooted in
Russia as in Western Europe. The ‘modern’ character of the factory
workforce seemed to call for industrial unionism, and the socialists
who led the union movement found this more politically appealing
than craft unionism. Although the reformist socialists were a powerful
influence in the unions at a national level, in Petrograd the Bolsheviks
and Mensheviks were fairly evenly balanced, with the influence of the
former growing rapidly. Given their large size and the inhospitable
conditions in which they began to operate, the unions proved
themselves surprisingly effective as organisations representing the
interests of workers as a whole. It was only after October, when the
unions became subject to the Bolshevik government, that bureaucra-
tisation developed on a significant scale.

Accelerating inflation rapidly undermined the wage-gains which


workers had made in the spring, largely by means of small-scale,
localised struggles. The unions sought to restore the real wages of
workers by negotiating city-wide contracts covering all workers in
each branch of industry. The contracts aimed to improve the position
of the low-paid, in part by diminishing wage-differentials, and so
many low-paid workers joined the unions in the summer of 1917.
Negotiations of the contracts were often protracted, however, and as
the position of the low-paid grew progressively worse, they turned
increasingly to unofficial direct action in an effort to defend them-
selves against rocketing inflation. This brought some sections of the
rank-and-file into conflict with union leaders - conflict which was
exacerbated when the compromises made between union negotiators
and the employers became known. There was considerable opposi-
tion to the final terms of the metal contract, for example, because
ferocious inflation had eaten away the value of the wage increases by
the time the contract was signed. Given the intractability of the
economic crisis, it was probably an achievement for the unions to
have succeeded in implementing the contracts at all. The contracts,
by rationalising the pay structure, by setting-up rates commissions
and, above all, by linking wages to productivity, prefigured aspects of
Bolshevik labour-policy after 1917. And within the metal union a




‘productivist’ current, which celebrated efficiency, planning and the
‘culture of production’, adumbrated the movement for the ‘scientific
organisation of labour’ which was to develop in the 1920s.

The deepening crisis of the economy provides the backdrop to the


political radicalisation of Petrograd workers. The inability, or-
perceived unwillingness, of the Kerensky government to protect the
gains made by workers after the February Revolution, led to growing
disillusionment with the moderate socialists who supported the
government. Workers now began to look to their own organisations
for protection. It was the movement for workers’ control of produc-
tion which translated growing economic discontent into sympathy for
the Bolshevik party. Workers’ control had its roots in the democra-
tisation of factory life, but the main impulse behind the movement
sprang from the efforts of the factory committees to maintain
production and to defend jobs — at a time when massive redundancies
and the collapse of the war industries loomed on the horizon. Initially,
the scope of workers’ control was fairly modest: it aimed to supervise
the activities of management in order to ensure that it did not
‘sabotage’ production or endanger workers’ jobs. As economic
disorder and class conflict grew, however, the factory committees
broadened the scope of control. No longer did they confine themselves
to procuring fuel and raw materials and to inspecting the process of
production, they increasingly intervened in every sphere of manage-
ment decision-making, demanding the right to attend board meetings
and access to financial accounts and order-books. Although the
movement aimed to limit the power of management, it cannot be
considered a ‘syndicalist’ movement, for the determination of the
committees to combat ‘sabotage’ was motivated more by practical
than ideological considerations. Within Petrograd, anarchist and
syndicalist influence was limited, and conceptions of workers’ control
were not articulated in syndicalist terms at either factory level or on
the CCFC.7 Whilst the committees rejected Menshevik and SR calls
for state control of the economy, they endorsed Bolshevik perspectives
for centralised coordination of the economy by a proletarian state
power. There were, however, differences of emphasis between the
leaders of the factory committees, the majority of whom were
Bolsheviks, and the official party spokesmen. Committee activists
appear to have had more faith in the capacity of grass-roots control to
restore order in the economy than did some party leaders. Moreover
they linked the battle to combat economic disorder to the struggle to




limit the prerogatives of the employers and, consequently, placed
much greater emphasis than did most party leaders on the necessity of
transforming authority-relations at enterprise level, as part of the
transition to socialism.

It would be wrong, however, to conclude that the Bolsheviks


cynically manipulated the factory committees for their own ends. The
radicalisation of the movement for workers’ control gave the party
enormous opportunity to win wide support for its policies, but it did
not control the movement: it responded to it, trying to steer it in the
direction it believed was proper. It was the organised working class,
not the Bolshevik party, which was the great power in society — more
powerful than even the capitalist class, as its success in resisting
redundancies suggests. The collapse of the system of war capitalism,
however, in early 1918 destroyed the strength of the working class,
and it was only at that point that the Bolsheviks were in a position to
achieve a monopoly of power.

The advent to power of the Bolsheviks in October raised the hopes


and aspirations of workers in a similar way to the February
Revolution, yet it made little difference to their working lives, for the
economic situation continued to get worse. Initially, Lenin supported
a radical interpretation of the Decree on Workers’ Control, although
he did not envisage a rapid transition to a socialist economy.
Gradually, however, he became convinced that workers’ control
could not cope with the deep structural crisis of the economy, and he
came to side with the trade-union critics of the factory committees.
The Bolsheviks on the CCFC favoured a speedy transition to
socialism, and they were the most vocal section of the party pressing
for a system of central economic planning and state ownership of
industry. Under such a system, the factory-committee Bolsheviks
envisaged that workers’ control would be transmuted into workers’
management of individual enterprises. At factory level, many com-
mittee activists saw the Decree on Workers’ Control as opening the
way to workers’ self-management, but in practice most of the
control-commissions set up by the Decree confined themselves to
circumscribing drastically the power of management, whilst not
displacing it altogether. In the circumstances, this policy did not
prove workable. Most employers resisted the more ambitious style of
workers’ control, and preferred to close down their factories rather
than to submit to it. As a result, in a few instances, the control-
commissions were forced to take over the actual running of the




factories in a vain effort to save jobs. Such takeovers — although
occurring in only a minority of Petrograd factories - were crucial in
pushing the government in the direction of full-scale nationalisation.
‘Nationalisations from below’, together with escalating chaos in
industry, persuaded the government finally to nationalise the whole
of industry in June 1918. This proved, however, not to be the
realisation of self-management, as the factory-committee activists
had expected, but the first step in a process which culminated in the
full restoration of one-man management.

There is some indication that prior to October the factory


committees were beginning to accept the idea of a merger with the
trade unions, but after October conflict between the two organisa-
tions flared up, as both tried to compete in the business of regulating
the economy. The factory committees were accused by the unions of
being selfish, parochial organisations, unsuited to the broad tasks of
restoring order to the economy. Instances of such parochialism were
in fact few in Petrograd, but there were just enough examples of
committees refusing to share precious stocks of fuel and raw materials
(at the Metal, Triangle and Copper-Rolling works)8 to make the
trade-union charges stick. There is no real evidence that the
committees were exacerbating the chaos in the economy, as the
unions claimed, but nor were they managing to cope with it, as they
claimed they could. As the factories closed down, and as hundreds of
thousands of workers fled from Petrograd, centralism and firm
discipline became the order of the day. Only the unions seemed
capable of achieving these things. Consequently, the government
decided that the factory committees must be absorbed into the
apparatus of the trade unions.

By the spring of 1918, Lenin was haunted by the fact that the


economic infrastructure of socialism did not exist in Russia. The
political superstructure was there, in the shape of a soviet govern-
ment, but not the material base. This existed only in the West - above
all, in Germany. This led him to observe that: ‘History has taken such
a peculiar course that it has given birth to two unconnected halves of
socialism, existing side by side like two future chickens in a single shell
of international imperialism. In 1918 Germany has become the most
striking embodiment of the material realisation of the economic,
productive and socio-economic conditions for socialism on the one
hand, and Russia, the embodiment of the political conditions on the




other.’9 The Treaty of Brest Litovsk signalled the fact that revolution
would not break out immediately in Germany. Every effort, therefore,
had to be made to build up the productive forces in Russia. As Lenin
argued:

The task of the day is to restore the productive forces destroyed by the war
and by bourgeois rule; to heal the wounds inflicted by the war and by the
defeat in the war, by profiteering and the attempts of the bourgeoisie to
restore the overthrown rule of the exploiters; to achieve economic revival; to
provide reliable protection of elementary order. It may sound paradoxical,
but, in fact, considering the objective conditions mentioned, it is absolutely
certain that at the present moment the Soviet system can secure Russia’s
transition to socialism only if these very elementary, extremely elementary
problems of maintaining public life are practically solved.10

This meant, first and foremost, raising the productivity of labour: ‘the


Russian worker is a bad worker in comparison with the advanced
nations ... To learn to work is the task that the Soviet government
must set the people in all its scope.’11 In turn, this meant the
restoration of ‘iron discipline’ in the workplace, the revival of
piece-rates, productivity deals and, above all, one-man management.

Implicit within the movement for workers’ control was a belief that


capitalist methods cannot be used for socialist ends. In their battle to
democratise the factory, in their emphasis on the importance of
collective initiatives by the direct producers in transforming the
work-situation, the factory committees had become aware — in a
partial and groping way, to be sure - that factories are not merely sites
of production, but also of reproduction — the reproduction of a certain
structure of social relations based on the division between those who
give orders and those who take them, between those who direct and
those who execute. The leaders of the factory committees never
developed these insights into a systematic strategy for socialism,
alternative to that of Lenin and the majority of the Bolshevik
leadership; yet inscribed within their practice was a distinctive vision
of socialism, central to which was workplace democracy.

Lenin believed that socialism could be built only on the basis of


large-scale industry as developed by capitalism, with its specific types
of productivity and social organisation of labour. Thus for him,
capitalist methods of labour-discipline or one-man management were
not necessarily incompatible with socialism. Indeed, he went so far as
to consider them to be inherently progressive, failing to recognise that
such methods undermined workers’ initiatives at the point of
production. This was because Lenin believed that the transition to




socialism was guaranteed, ultimately, not by the self-activity of
workers, but by the ‘proletarian’ character of the state power.

Maurice Brinton, the libertarian critic of Bolshevism, has exposed


the inadequacy of his conception:

None of them [i.e. the Bolshevik leaders] saw the proletarian nature of the
Russian regime as primarily and crucially dependent on the exercise of
workers’ power at the point of production (i.e. on workers’ management of
production). It should have been obvious to them as Marxists that if the
working class did not hold economic power, its ‘political’ power would at best
be insecure and would in fact soon degenerate. The Bolshevik leaders saw the
capitalist organisation of production as something which, in itself, was
socially neutral. It could be used indifferently for
bad
purposes (as when the
bourgeoisie used it with the aim of promoting private accumulation) or
good
ones (as when the ‘workers” state used it ‘for the benefit of many’).12

This critique is absolutely on target. There is no doubt that Lenin did


conceive proletarian power in terms of the central state and lacked a
conception of localising such power at the point of production.13

A more far-reaching critique of Bolshevik strategy at this time has


been developed by writers of Maoist persuasion - principally, the
French economist Charles Bettelheim. He argues that the Bolsheviks
were wrong to believe that the possibility of socialist advance is, in
any sense, determined by the level of productive forces. He follows
Mao Zedong in arguing that the transformation of relations of
production clears the way for the development of productive forces
rather than vice versa.14 He contends that because the Bolsheviks -
with the heroic exception of Lenin, whom he unwarrantedly excludes
from his strictures — erroneously believed that the level of productive
forces dictates the possibilities of socialist advance, they therefore
subordinated the transformation of capitalist social relations to the
drive to increase industrial output. The consequent absence of a
strategy for transforming work-relations meant that output increased
within a framework of capitalist rather than socialist relations of
production. The capitalist division of labour and the ideological and
political relations which are an effect of this division, were thus
constantly reproduced, paving the way, Bettelheim avers, for the
ultimate restoration of a ‘state bourgeoisie’.

There is much in Bettelheim’s stimulating critique with which one


can agree. The Bolshevik strategy of transition did indeed centre on
building the ‘economic base’ (‘socialism equals electrification plus
soviet power’), with little attention being paid to transforming social
relations. But in denying that the level of productive forces exercises




any constraint on the possibilities of socialist advance, Bettelheim is
guilty of the grossest voluntarism. The implication of his argument is
that the subsequent development of the Soviet state was the
consequence of a simple theoretical error (‘economism’). Whilst he
mentions the intractable economic and social circumstances in which
the Bolsheviks found themselves, these objective constraints do not
really function as part of his explanation of the degeneration of the
revolution.

A satisfactory examination of the theoretical relationship of forces


of production to relations of production, would take us into rarefied
spheres well outside the scope of this work. Marx centrally assumed
that the creation of socialist relations of production was possible only
on the basis of a certain level of productive forces, but his treatment of
this question is problematical, because his concept of the ‘productive
forces’ at times smacks of technological determinism. This led the
Second International to interpret the question in a way that was
unambiguously technological-determinist. Theoreticians such as K.
Kautsky conceived the ‘productive forces’ as technology and the
ever-growing scale of production. They argued that these, being
social in character, would come into ever-increasing conflict with the
constricting mode of appropriation based on private ownership.
Finally, the productive forces would burst the fetters of private
ownership, but would provide the material base for a socialist
reorganisation of society, once a socialist government came to power.
It is possible, however, to find in Marx’s writings, a broader
conception of ‘productive forces’, which does not reduce them to
technology or productive capacity. This conceives productive forces
as all those capacities and resources which are harnessed to
producing use-values. These forces, which can never be divorced
from the social forms in which they are embodied, include not merely
types of industrial and agricultural production, but modes of social
cooperation, the application of knowledge and cultural forms.15
Above all, Marx sees the principal ‘productive force’ as being the
working class itself.16 In the light of this broader conception, it
becomes clearer why Marx considered that a developed level of
productive forces was necessary to the construction of socialism; for
only a high level of productive forces could make possible the big
reduction in necessary labour time which would enable the whole
people to participate in self-government and civilisation. Without an
adequate level of productive forces, ‘want is merely made general




and, with destitution, the struggle for necessities and all the old filthy
business is necessarily reproduced’.17 Socialism, in other words,
would cease to be the entry into freedom, and become a struggle for
survival instead.

With this in mind, it is possible to understand the cruel dilemma in


which the Bolsheviks found themselves in 1918. They were intent on
creating democratic socialism, but their priority had to be the
reconstruction of the productive forces, especially, the revival of
labour-discipline. In the short term, the limited use of forms of
compulsion, in particular, the application of capitalist methods of
labour-discipline and labour-intensification, was probably unavoid-
able. Yet most of the Bolshevik leadership seemed unaware of the
dangers posed to the goal of democratic socialism by the long-term
use of methods which undermined workers’ self-activity in produc-
tion. This was largely a consequence of the ideological problematic
within which they thought through the problems of socialist construc-
tion. This problematic - still, in large part, that which had been
inherited from the Second International - construed the productive
forces in a narrow, technicist fashion and conceived the types of
productivity and social organisation of labour engendered by capital-
ist society as being inherently progressive. Moreover within this
problematic the absence of a notion of workers’ self-activity in the
realm of production as being a constituent element of socialist
transition was especially glaring. If the Bolsheviks had been more
critical of this Second International problematic, it is possible that
they would have been more alive to the dangers of using coercive
methods to restore the battered productive forces, except as an
emergency measure. Whether such an awareness could have pre-
vented the degeneration of the democratic socialist revolution in the
long term, however, as Bettelheim suggests - given the persistence of
war, economic isolation and cultural backwardness - seems doubtful.
The depressing experience of socialist societies to date suggests that
the imperatives of economic and social development in under-
developed societies necessitate types of compulsion which ultimately
conflict with the creation of free social relations. In other words, even
if the Bolshevik government had been more percipient concerning the
dangers to democratic socialism posed by the methods which it was
forced to adopt, it seems probable that objective circumstances would
ultimately have conspired to drain socialism of its democratic
content. As it was, blind to the risks that it was running, the




government was very quickly forced along a path which in October
1917 it had never dreamed of traversing. Already by 1921, the
Bolsheviks no longer represented a socialism of liberty, but one of
scarcity, in which the needs of individual and human liberation were
firmly subordinate to the exigencies of economic development.


Notes

INTRODUCTION

  1. T. Skocpol, States and Social Revolutions (Cambridge University Press,
    1979) > Revolutions in Modern European History, ed. H. Lubasz (New York,
    Macmillan, 1976).


  2. Excellent accounts of the general developments of the Russian Revolution
    are available in the following works: J.L.H. Keep,
    The Russian Revolution: a
    study in mass mobilisation
    (London, Weidenfeld and Nicolson, 1976); M.
    Ferro,
    The Russian Revolution ofFebruary 73/7 (London, Routledge, 1972); M.
    Ferro,
    October igiy (London, Routledge, 1980). The July Days are
    examined in A. Rabinowitch,
    Prelude to Revolution (Bloomington, Indiana
    University Press, 1968). The October insurrection has two fine histories in
    R.V. Daniels,
    Red October: the Bolshevik Revolution of igiy (New York,
    Scribners, 1967) and A. Rabinowitch,
    The Bolsheviks Come to Power (New
    York, Norton, 1976). Although the present study discusses briefly the
    policies of the major political parties on ‘economic’ affairs, an attempt has
    been made to avoid duplicating the comprehensive accounts already
    available in P. Avrich,
    The Russian Revolution and the Factory Committees
    (Columbia University, Ph.D., 1962); R.J. Devlin, Petrograd Workers and
    Workers’ Factory Committees
    (State University of New York at Binghampton,
    Ph.D., 1976).


  3. N. Poulantzas, Classes in Contemporary Capitalism (London, New Left Books,

  1. ; N. Poulantzas, State, Power and Socialism (London, New Left Books,

  1. ; R. Hyman, Industrial Relations: a Marxist Introduction (London,
    Macmillan, 1975), p.26; S. Lukes,
    Power: a Radical View (London,
    Macmillan, 1974), PP-
    34~5-

  1. V.I. Lenin, ‘What is to be done?’, Selected Works (in two volumes), vol.i
    (London, Lawrence and Wishart, 1946).


  2. C. Goodrich, The Frontier of Control (London, Pluto Press, 1975).

  3. Spisok fabrichno-zavodskikh predpriyatii Petrograda (Petrograd, 1918), pp.7
    -16.

NOTES TO CHAPTER I



  1. Material))po statistike Petrograda, issue 1 (Petrograd, 1920), p. 10. Estimates
    vary from 2.3 million to 2.7 million. A.G. Rashin,
    Formirovanie rabochego
    klassa Rossii
    (Moscow, 1958), p.354; S.G. Strumilin, ‘Obshchii obzor
    severnoi oblasti’,
    Materialy po statistike truda sevemoi oblasti, issue 1
    (Petrograd, 1918), p.17.


  2. A.G. Rashin, Naselenie Rossii z.a sto let (Moscow, 1956), pp.25, 97.

  3. Mat. po stat. Pet., issue 1, p. 10.

  4. E.E. Kruze and D.G. Kutsentov, ‘Naselenie Peterburga’ in Ocherki istorii
    Leningrada,
    vol.3 (Moscow, 1956), p.106.

  5. A more detailed statistical discussion of the demographic structure of St
    Petersburg can be found in: S.A. Smith,
    The Russian Revolution and the
    Factories of Petrograd, February igiy to June igi8,
    Ph.D. (Birmingham
    University, 1980), pp.2-5. These generalisations are based on Rashin,
    Naselenie-, and Mat. po. stat. Pet., issue 1.

  6. Statisticheskie dannye Petrograda (Petrograd, 1916), p.8.

  7. Kruze and Kutsentov, ‘Naselenie’, pp. 104-46.

  8. P.V. Volobuev, Proletariat i burzhuaziya Rossii v lgijg. (Moscow, 1964),
    P-
    47-

  9. Oktyabr'skoe vooruzhennoe vosstanie, ed. S.N. Valk, vol.i (Leningrad, 1967),
    P-
    47-

  10. ibid., pp.419-21.

  11. P.I. Lyashchenko, History of the National Economy of Russia (New York,
    Macmillan, 1949), p. 714.


  12. Oktyabr'skoe vooruzhennoe vosstanie, vol.i, p.423.

  13. M.E. Falkus, The Industrialisation of Russia, iyoo-igi4 (London, Mac-
    millan, 1972), pp.77-8.


  14. Oktyabr'skoe vooruzhennoe vosstanie, vol.i, pp.403-5.

  15. Spisok fabrichno-zavodskikh predpriyatii Petrograda (Petrograd, 1918);
    lstoricheskii arkhiv, 5, 1961, 158-65.

  16. Oktyabr'skoe vooruzhennoe vosstanie, vol.i, pp.408—9.

  17. O. Crisp, ‘Labour and Industrialisation in Russia’, Cambridge Economic
    History of Europe,
    vol. vii,
    Yüklə 4,02 Mb.

    Dostları ilə paylaş:
1   ...   18   19   20   21   22   23   24   25   ...   32




Verilənlər bazası müəlliflik hüququ ilə müdafiə olunur ©muhaz.org 2024
rəhbərliyinə müraciət

gir | qeydiyyatdan keç
    Ana səhifə


yükləyin